Offshore
EXCLUSIVE INTERVIEW: Making Beneficial Ownership Public Carries Risks, Academic Warns
The idea of putting beneficial ownership information in the public domain is a popular one. But such an idea should be thoroughly examined, says an Australia-based academic specialising in this field.
A topic that is all the rage in the world of international financial centres is “beneficial ownership”. The issue is complex and controversial because public registers are, so some jurisdictions such as the British Virgin Islands fear, a threat to legitimate client privacy.
It is by no means self-evident that public registers will be the silver bullet to stop flows of illicit funds, an Australia-based academic, Jason Sharman of Griffith University, argued recently. A recent report (see here), commissioned by Jersey Finance, questions the efficacy of public registers and urges the financial industry to consider the case for corporate service providers (CSPs) as a point of regulatory intervention instead. This publication recently interviewed Sharman about his report and where he thinks progress can be made.
Please explain your background and how you got to be
working in this area.
I began looking at tax havens and the OECD harmful tax
competition initiative in 2002, an interest that subsequently
developed into looking at anti-money laundering policy, and then
anti-corruption. In all three areas - tax, anti-money laundering
and countering large scale corruption - beneficial ownership is
key.
In broad terms, what is your opinion of how policymakers
in many countries are addressing the beneficial ownership
question?
This varies by country: the US is in denial about the inadequacy
of its beneficial ownership regulations, whereas in the European
Union and UK this issue is rightly seen as important and urgent.
Less positively there is a rather uncritical faith in centralised
registries of beneficial ownership as a silver bullet, and a
corresponding neglect of enforcing regulations mandating that
intermediaries establish beneficial ownership.
What is the main argument against public registers of
beneficial ownership and why?
The main argument against centralised registries of beneficial
ownership is that this solution is largely untested, and that it
relies on unverified self-declarations of beneficial ownership.
Public registries are also accused by some of violating privacy.
How serious are the risks that public registers can
imperil legitimate financial privacy and put people at
risk?
It depends what legitimate financial privacy is; standards
have been shifting very quickly here. Rightly or wrongly, it is
now seen that citizens have no right to keep their financial
affairs private from the state. Public registries now mean that
in addition there is some expectation of transparency to all and
sundry as well. To me this is in striking contrast with European
data protection principles, which are strongly premised on the
expectation that individuals control information about them, and
with narrow exceptions that these individuals choose what
information about them becomes public or stays private.
Your report mentioned what you see as the potential and
actual benefits of using corporate service providers. What makes
them an effective tool?
If you mean the benefits of CSPs as a point of regulatory
intervention, it is because CSPs have a substantive relationship
with clients, and a strong incentive to accurately establish and
verify beneficial ownership for fear of penalties, as long as
regulators are actually enforcing standards here.
Where, in terms of jurisdictions, do you see the
approaches you most favour and what are they doing
right?
According to the evidence I collected with Michael Findley and
Daniel Nielson for our book Global Shell Games,
jurisdictions like the Cayman Islands and Jersey are best at
ensuring the transparency of companies created in those
jurisdictions. Again, licensed and regulated CSPs seem to be the
key, with actual enforcement via audits and sanctions rather than
laws on the books being the name of the game.
Where in your view are countries making
mistakes?
Countries are making mistakes by investing faith in new rules at
a time when they are not enforcing old ones, e.g. the UK with the
third EU AML directive.
In an age of big data and other technological advances,
how do such tech trends make it easier or harder to track
beneficial owners?
Big data and the ease of copying and transporting information
obviously make leaks and data dumps easier, but there is a
surprising lack of correlation between authorities having more
information and greater policy effectiveness.
If governments want to enhance disclosure, what
safeguards should they have in place to protect legitimate
privacy?
The main problem here is that many governments have stigmatised
any use of any offshore vehicle at the same time as they have
called for greater transparency. If people are going to suffer
reputational damage for any association with offshore, this will
mean they are less rather than more likely to disclose. To this
extent Cameron's problem with his father's Bahamian trust are
poetic justice.
How in your view can jurisdictions get the balance right
between privacy and secrecy? Are developments such as the Common
Reporting Standard and FATCA achieving this, or not?
People and governments need to take a step back and decide
what legitimate expectations of financial privacy are, if any,
and then assess whether existing policies comply or not. Until
recently the de facto standard was that citizens had no right to
financial privacy vis-à-vis the state, but did have quite strong
rights vis-à-vis everyone else. Public registries begin to weaken
this.