Investment Strategies
GUEST ARTICLE: The Wealth Of Nations

This article looks at some potentially troubling long-term economic trends and what they mean for future prosperity.
In this article from Subitha Sabramaniam, chief economist at
Sarasin & Partners, the author takes a step back from some of the
more immediate issues, such as Brexit, deceleration in China or
the state of monetary policy, to look at longer term economic and
social trends in many economies. Wealth managers, when they
allocate clients’ assets and consider the kind of goals clients
have, must sometimes be willing to take a wide view. We hope this
article is of interest to readers and invite
responses.
Janet Yellen, the chairwoman of the Federal Reserve’s Board of
Governors, has been extraordinarily cautious about raising rates.
What is worrying her? For sure, the economic recovery from the
depths of the financial crisis has been lacklustre; but
recoveries after deep credit crises are typically anaemic. Over
the past seven years, unemployment in the US has steadily
declined and while inflation might not be roaring ahead, it is
comfortably within the reaches of its midterm mandate.
So, why is she concerned?
A central bank today is very much a post war institution – built
to navigate a world of supportive demographics and successful
innovation waves. For much of the past 30 years, the prevailing
dogma has been that if policymakers focused on price stability
and minimised cyclical volatility, a country could comfortably
achieve its economic potential. Economic growth would follow its
pre-ordained trend built upon demographics and innovation.
In recent years, however, demographic forces have weakened
considerably and labour productivity seems mired in a post-crisis
torpor. With many inexorable trends grinding to a halt, Yellen’s
caution stems from a concern that the listless economic recovery
represents a deeper economic malaise - one where the cyclical
recovery is struggling to gain momentum because of a downward
shift in trend growth. In such an environment, it is exceedingly
difficult to extricate cyclical impulses from a shift in trend
and harder still to assess the "natural rate of
interest" for the economy.
Adam Smith, in his sprawling work, An Inquiry into the Nature
and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, postulated that a
country’s output is generated by its workers and in proportion to
their productivity. Over the years, his thesis has become one of
the central principles of classical economics. Every year,
individuals, businesses and policymakers invest sizeable
resources in generating, managing and measuring the flow of
output (gross domestic product) that stems from the country’s
workers. Financial markets, which reflect the profitability of
such enterprise, ebb and flow with the rise and fall of this
measured output.
While short- and long-term investors have distinctively different
approaches to identifying investment opportunities, both are
driven by the flow of output. Short-term investors are more
likely to try to arbitrage short-term deviation of output from a
long-term trend, while longer term investors are likely to focus
on the trend itself. For all investors, though, clarity over the
long-term trend is critical.
So, how do we estimate the long-term trend?
A common approach is to use an average over a long time period.
There are good reasons for this. Advanced economies like the US
or the UK, which are considered to be at the technology frontier,
have an "organic" rate of innovation. This is the pace at
which they create and synthesise successive innovation waves. It
is the pace at which standards of living typically improve.
Chart 1, which plots the average pace of productivity growth in
the US over a five-, 10- and 65-year period, demonstrates that
over more finite periods of say five to 10 years there can be
substantial deviations from long run averages. While productivity
averaged 1.8 per cent over the entire 65 year period, during a
five-year time frame, it has been as high as 3.2 per cent and as
low as 0.3 per cent. More generally, we can also see that the
aftermath of productivity surges create exceedingly challenging
backdrops for the economy and financial markets. This has been
particularly true for Japan - where the country entered a deep
slump following the remarkable productivity surge of the 1970s
(chart 2). Japan has since lost two decades and now
appears to be stuck in secular stagnation.
So, how can we know the type of productivity regime (and
therefore growth regime) we are likely to encounter over the
coming decade? Are there any signposts that can alert us to an
impending shift like the one that Japan encountered?
How to assess a country’s wealth?
There are no easy answers. However, in times of flux and
uncertainty, we believe that it is very helpful to go back to
basics. Given that economic growth, or the flow of output, is
generated by the asset base or the "wealth of a nation",
assessing the asset base of a country can be very useful.
How do we assess the health of a country’s capital base? Smith
defined the capital base as “That part of a man’s stock which he
expects to afford him revenue”. In today’s terminology, this
would include the stock of a country’s physical capital (plant,
equipment, machinery, computers, software etc.), human capital
(education, training), socio-political capital (democratic
institutions, rule of law), natural capital (finite resources)
and financial capital (risk taking and sharing). A smaller asset
base will typically generate a smaller flow of output.
How do "stock" variables in today’s world stack up? Let’s
start with the most easily measured – the stock of a country’s
physical capital. Through time, the flow of output from a
country’s workers has always been proportional to the amount of
physical capital that workers have access to.
Moreover, a healthy economy is typically one that increases its
stock of physical capital per worker over time. Charts 3 and 4
show the evolution of the stock of physical capital per worker in
the US and in Japan. Since the financial crisis, there appear to
be some dramatic shifts underway. Capital stock per worker, which
had steadily risen throughout the post-war period, plateaued
after the financial crisis and in the US has been stagnating for
about five years now. In other words, businesses appear to have
stopped investing in their workers. This is indeed worrying,
because Japan’s economic stagnation over the past two decades has
been accompanied by a plateau/decline in the capital stock per
worker.
Another marker for evaluating the health of a country’s capital
stock is to evaluate its contribution to growth. In the US, the
Congressional Budget Office (CBO) calculates the contribution to
potential growth from the country’s capital base – it calls this
the “capital input” into trend growth. In Chart 5, you can see
that there have been two surges in “capital input” - similar to
what was experienced by productivity. And in keeping with the
broader productivity data, there has been a dramatic and
worrisome drop off in recent years.
Why are the physical capital bases of advanced economies
declining?
There are possibly two interconnected forces at play
here. First, the demand patterns of post-industrial
societies appear to be shifting away from physical goods towards
services and virtual goods (information, media, data,
entertainment etc.). As demand for physical goods ebbs, so too
has the need for physical capital. If we study the shift in
consumption patterns in the US between 1987 and 2016, in
this 30-year period, 8.5 per cent of the consumer’s wallet has
migrated away from physical goods (cars, white goods, clothing
etc.) towards services which are increasingly tilted towards
information, media and entertainment. Some economists, like Larry
Summers, call this phenomena demassification – or a reduction in
the consumption of “stuff”. The economy as a whole is moving away
from making and consuming goods where it is easier to improve and
measure improvements toward the service sector where it is
exceptionally difficult to increase and measure productivity.
Second, in this post-industrial society, physical capital is
being substituted away by human or intellectual capital. Platform
business models (which often benefit from hyper scale and network
advantages) are increasing the utilisation rates of existing
assets and reducing the need for more physical investments. For
example, ecommerce is continuing to reduce the demand for
shopping malls; platforms like AirB&B and Uber are chipping
away at the demand for hotels and automobiles.
These shifts have been underway for decades and are likely to
endure. As consumption patterns gyrate towards virtual goods and
services, the capital bases of advanced economies are likely to
stagnate and possibly decline. The estimates of productivity and
trend growth are also likely to remain far below long-term
averages.
Assessing the health of the other capital assets that underpin
the economy – financial, socio-political and natural capital -
are big topics in themselves. At a very simplistic level, we can
conclude that financial capital base of advanced economies has
been weakened by central bank intervention, which have distorted
market prices and thereby the efficiency of capital allocation.
The socio-political capital of economies, which have risen
strongly after the end of the cold war, has recently been
besieged by the backlash against globalisation and rising
inequality. The consensus around the political centre is rapidly
disappearing - and with it political stability. Lastly, climate
risks highlight that the natural capital of the world is
precariously balanced and can easily lead to substantial
losses.
In sum, using a “wealth of nations” approach leads us to
believe that there is a strong case for productivity to remain
moribund and for trend growth to weaken. The world economy
appears to have entered a new regime of shifting demand and
challenging fundamentals. Moreover, Japan’s experience serves as
a cautionary tale of how in the absence of another meaningful
innovation wave, we could be entering a period of secular
stagnation.