Strategy
BOOK REVIEW: Free Lunch Thinking By Tom Bergin

A new book by a UK journalist challenges a number of economic ideas that he says have damaged living standards, fostered inequality and other problems. It describes the world that the wealth industry inhabits, and is sure to spark plenty of debate.
Free Lunch Thinking: How Economics Ruins the Economy is published by Penguin (377 pages). ISBN 978184794273-9
Do people respond to incentives? Are they rationally
self-interested most of the time? Are they sound judges of their
own interest? Do high taxes crush risk-taking? Do people quit
smoking or other “sins” if the price tag becomes extortionate?
Is regulation generally bad for growth?
Award-winning Reuters investigative journalist Tom
Bergin argues that the answer to these questions is “no” - with
caveats. Humans are far less responsive to incentives, such as
taxes, than is conventionally assumed, he says. And if he’s
correct (I will argue that he is only partly so), that creates a
big problem for free markets. It also suggests compulsion is the
only viable alternative in reaching a supposed desirable outcome
if hard work can’t get there. A gloomy thought in the Lockdown
Age.
Bergin argues that a number of influential economists and
writers, such as the late Milton Friedman and Arthur Laffer (he’s
still alive and kicking in his 80s) have over-egged the case for
incentives as a driver of behaviour; they have, according to
Bergin’s charge sheet, dramatically exaggerated the ability to
model human conduct, and put false, often ideologically-charged
faith in “neoclassical” models about supply and demand. While
their ideas are not without merit (Bergin is careful not to be
rude about these men, who are/were eminent, often admirable
people), the author of this 377-page book is pretty harsh. He
argues that ideas as varied as supply-side tax policy, money
supply targeting, sin taxes and CEO bonuses have been damaging
failures at worst or overblown at best. Nearly all of his
firepower is aimed at variants of free market thinking over the
period from WW2, although he takes a few swipes at forms of
statism. This is a very readable book, and it carries copious
footnotes (including one referring to your correspondent, who was
a colleague of Bergin at Reuters in the
Noughties).
A big plus from the book is how Bergin illustrates some of the
big policymaking controversies of past decades. Much of the world
in which wealth managers inhabit today was shaped by the people
in this book, which is why Bergin does a service in describing
it. In the section of the book in which I get a brief footnote
(page 214), Bergin writes about the events leading up to the
2008/09 financial crackup, and the development of the credit
derivatives market that was associated with it. (Tom and I used
to report on this sector, on credit default swaps and
collateralised debt obligations for example. It was fascinating
stuff. Yes, really!) He argues that among the likes of former Fed
chairman Alan Greenspan, confidence that banks and
others would follow their rational self-interest was
misplaced. That said, some of the problems weren't just lack of
regulation, but the unintended results of the regulations that
did exist, such as Basel capital rules, as well as forces
such as the "too big to fail" assumptions of commercial banks,
limited liability of banks' owners, dangerously conflicted rating
agency incentives, etc. Blame for the 2008 smash goes far and
wide.
Due to the limits of space I’m going to focus on my criticisms
and differences with some of the book’s claims. And even
though I disagree with some of the points here, I heartily
recommend this book because it challenges assumptions and lazy
thinking. There's much to admire.
Free lunches, models and theories
A particular charge of Bergin – which explains the book’s title –
is that while the likes of Milton Friedman were fond of the
statement “there’s no such thing as a free lunch,” in practice a
lot of these thinkers offered allegedly cost-free solutions. For
example, they supported the idea that tax cuts were
self-financing because they raised more revenue eventually, or
that tobacco taxes reduced cancer and therefore health bills.
There seems some truth in Bergin’s complaint although it is
arguably inevitable, given the pressures of politics, for people
to try and find the least painful "solutions" available.
Politicians want to be popular - it's easier for them to tax a
sinful activity, say, than ban it.
The central message of the book could be summed up as “beware
hubris of economic models.” But sometimes I think Bergin isn't
quite on the right track. Consider, he writes quite a lot about
how economists have been in thrall to the model of "perfect
competition." But few free market economists today really
think the “perfect competition” model describes reality (some
have even written it off as useless and downright misleading,
such as FA Hayek). It is an abstract model, nothing more. If the
conditions for perfect competition obtained, including that of
economic actors having complete information, we could have made
central planning work with enough computing power. In fact, the
imperfections of the real world – such as unmet wants and
incomplete information – are precisely why
entrepreneurial alertness for new opportunities is so
important. One person’s gap is another’s opportunity. Competition
is not a static game among omniscient geniuses, but a risk-taking
process through time involving fallible humans. (This is one of
the most important insights of the “Austrian” school of
economics.) (1)
Remember, state central planning presumes that the State has some
superhuman ability to foresee patterns of demand and supply
and do so better than individuals operating in the alleged
“chaos” of a market. Let's just say history is not very kind to
central planning. Without the co-ordinating function of a state
plan, then, one has prices. Prices communicate
relative scarcity and plenitude. They matter, even if they
work in ways that don’t fit a narrow model. Prices are
information, not just ephemera. (Economics is in some ways a
study of information.)
All that said, Bergin appears to be sceptical over how useful prices are unless heavily qualified (such as when he discusses the minimum wage or tax rates.) If the incentives that come to play in a world of free economic agents don’t work in predictable ways, it is easy to see how people are tempted to go for coercion instead, such as forcing firms to pay staff a certain rate, or grant X or Y weeks paid leave, or order landlords to not charge more than so much rent, and so on. Take away the “incentive economy,” so to speak, and the alternative is increasingly a “coercion economy” - and all the officiousness and red tape that involves.
For the most part Bergin plays the part of the sceptic of others'
big claims, but some of his own views definitely come through. On
page 236, for example, the author challenges the claim made
by Chicago's George Stigler and Milton Friedman that
regulators could be "captured" by the very industries they
regulated, with firms using red tape to raise barriers to
entry and protect incumbents. Bergin says this is a "dark view of
government." The two men would have replied that they were being
realistic about human nature, based on a long study of what
actually happens.
Do prices really matter?
There are a lot of contentious claims in this book, even though
Bergin provides sources to back them up. Example: he
challenges the claim that minimum wages cause some
unemployment (with the odd caveat). But this stance can only
be stretched so far. The UK statutory minimum wage for those
aged 25 and above is £8.72 (2). Imagine that were to be doubled,
or even trebled. Is it really credible to think that this
would not reduce hiring? Supermarkets these days have
automated check-out machines because firms found it more
profitable to substitute capital for labour, quite possibly at
the cost of low-wage labour.
Another claim that Bergin makes is that there is no necessary
causal link between how much a state taxes and spends, and
economic growth, usually measured as gross domestic product.
(This raised the old correlation is not causation issue.) GDP
includes government outlays, so if there’s more government
spending, then voila! - GDP has gone up. Bergin states that
growth of GDP per capita in the US from the end of the Civil War
to 1913 was slightly lower in its growth rate than in the
1960-1970 decade. So the Big Government Swinging Sixties were
actually more dynamic than the Gilded Era of Rockefeller,
Carnegie and the rest, on this account (3). But what we want is
an explanation of the relative performance of the non-State
sectors, not simply GDP, which lumps government and private
sector together. Also, if the Big Government era of the 1960s was
a decent state of affairs, or at least not a hindrance, how come
this all went wrong in the 1970s, with the collapse of Bretton
Woods and the rest of it?
And as Bergin writes, the 1970s was a crucial decade when many
people were re-thinking economic assumptions. Friedman and
others, noting the combination of mass unemployment and
inflation, realised that conventional Keynesian models had broken
down. New business startup rates were on the floor, UK film stars
and rock musicians, as well as entrepreneurs and scientists, fled
high-tax UK for Switzerland and other places (they clearly were
influenced by taxes). We see this sort of process today: there is
an exodus of firms from California for states without local
income taxes such as Texas and Florida (Hewlett Packard, Oracle,
parts of Charles Schwab, etc).
He's insistent that tax rates don't greatly affect things such as how hard we work or what we do for a living, and to some extent, that is true, particularly with salaried roles where a few percentage points here or there hardly count. Most of us choose an occupation not simply because of post-tax income but because we want to do something interesting as well as earn enough to be comfortable. And in this Bergin is surely bang on. He writes (page 87-88): "The best career advice I ever got was to work hard. It's the recurring guidance I have received from the nuns, Christian Brothers and Jesuits who taught me since I was four years of age. I heard it on Bavarian automobile production lines, in New York restaurants, on Dublin derivative-dealing desks and in London newsrooms. No one ever said to vary your effort and investment in yourself based on changes in your remuneration. No one said take your foot off the pedal if your bonus disappoints, take a longer lunch hour if the raise you wanted doesn't come through, or don't bother doing night courses if the company cuts back on its discounted share purchase plan." (Emphasis mine.) Even here, he overstates this, I think - surely there are many readers who have changed jobs because they were disgruntled over a bonus or pay rise or to earn more - it is common currency in the financial services sector, for example. When the UK was hit by strikes in the 1970s, that was one big demonstration that people do "vary your effort" based on pay. And I haven't met a journalist yet who doesn't moan about pay!
Do taxes actually encourage risk-taking?
There are a few other not-quite-right arguments in my
view. For instance, on page 69 Bergin claims that: “For
entrepreneurs or people investing in new enterprises,
theoretical work stretching back to the
1940s holds that taxes actually
encourage risk-taking, because, as
losses can be set against a tax bill, risk is effectively being
shared with the government. Lower tax rates, by contrast, place
more of the downside on the entrepreneur or investor.” (Italics
mine.) Hang on: I thought the premise of this book is that people
aren’t simple rational economic optimisers, and cannot
be boiled down into a theory, so what is Bergin doing referring
to “theoretical work” at all? Isn't he making the same mistake,
in the other direction, of a Laffer?
Consider this: why not take this argument further and
impose even higher taxes on everyone so that this
will encourage millions of people to quit regular jobs and
become the next Elon Musk by using a business as a tax shelter?
The problem with this argument, in my view, is that
it ignores the importance of time. A would-be
entrepreneur’s willingness to work for years, often at a loss
that could be set off against a tax bill, is not infinite unless
they are running that firm as a pure lifestyle choice rather than
to grow it. A business founder will want to plough back profits
into the business to grow - that's obviously harder to do if
the State takes a big slice of those earnings. A growth-minded
businesman or woman will not be much consoled by the State giving
them a tax break during a bad year. In the early stages of a
firm, it's particularly important that earnings can be
reinvested, and quickly. High taxes curb that. That seems
self-evident.
(As an aside, it is true that there are people who can be
“lifestyle entrepreneurs” taking this course for the sheer fun of
it, profits be damned. But it seems unlikely that high tax rates
on profits would not make people think harder about bothering
with the risks in the first place, not to mention putting
in the endless hours of trying to build a firm, working
over weekends, managing hassles of payroll, suppliers,
bureaucrats, etc (4).)
In one chapter Bergin challenges whether tax cuts shift attitudes towards work and leisure. He is right that when people get better off, they don't necessarily work even harder - they want a higher quality of life, including more time for leisure. But if their incomes are taxed more heavily, then while they may still want a holiday, they will have less money to spend on those trips to the South of France or Disneyland.
Top-down or bottom-up best practice?
Bergin argues against the idea of thinking of regulation as
purely a cost that should be cut. He notes, quite correctly, that
humans impose costs on unwitting others (water and air pollution,
risks to life from badly-made cars, etc) and that the
benefits of avoiding these harms must be weighed. He also argues
that regulation can spur innovation that wouldn’t otherwise have
happened. The latter point maybe true, although its not
conclusive. Much activity in wealth management is about using
technology, for example, to remove the pain of compliance. How
much of that activity could be spent on building wealth
instead?
In wealth industry, regulations have mushroomed – the SEC Regulation Best Interest regime (US), Dodd-Frank (US), MiFID II (European Union), Retail Distribution Review (UK), Senior Managers’ Regime (UK), and others around the world. Part of the justification is that Joe Public is in an unequal contest for information as a consumer, so the State must level the field. It is unclear whether the internet and other technologies have changed the game one way or the other. Whether the end-investor and consumer of banking and asset management services ends up better off after all these rules, is debatable. (The compliance industry has certainly boomed, mind.) I am unaware of any sustained cost/benefit analyses to say all this action has been a net plus for where it counts. Your correspondent has heard wealth managers – particularly the largest ones – claim that regulation simply spreads “best practice” to everybody. But without a degree of easement for smaller firms, red tape inevitably weighs proportionately more on the little guy. In fact regulation creates what economists call barriers to entry and cuts competition. And competition is surely the best protection consumers have.
We should distinguish State from non-State regulation. A company
or voluntary association will have its rules; violators can be
expelled. If you join an entity, you sign up for its regulations.
Also, a big driver of standards is insurance – and
Bergin doesn’t really mention this point. An insurer might, for
example, only cover risks where a person has taken certain steps
(fitting locks, replacing worn tyres on a car, etc) and that can
drive standards up. Beware the fine print! It may well be
that State rules can codify what the market has already set as
good conduct. But rules can also ossify, particularly if vested
interests are pushing them. And for all that Bergin concedes that
regulations can sometimes be a burden, he doesn’t really spell
out how to set the upper limits. A good idea in my view is
sunset clauses on State rules – particularly for those enacted
decades ago for activities that are defunct. The “regulation is
good” argument requires governments to have the wisdom to see all
sides of a question and not to fall into the trap of
“safety-first”. The current lockdowns suggest that governments
aren’t immune to getting this badly wrong.
Comparisons are hard
As Bergin argues, one problem in measuring economic ideas and
treating them as if they were scientific theories is that unlike,
say, Newton's Law of Gravitation, economics is ultimately about
human relationships, and these cannot be tested and retested in a
controlled lab experiment. The nearest one can get is comparing
similar countries/cultures undergoing very different policies,
holding some factors constant, and then working out what worked
better. That's very hard to do. Some writers have attempted to do
this, such as Germany-based academic and real estate investor Dr
Rainer Zitelmann (5). One can compare former East and West
Germany, North and South Korea, Chile and Venezuela, Hong Kong
and mainland China (prior to 1997), 1970s Britain against 1990s
Britain, and so on. These comparisons need to be done carefully,
with lots of health warnings, but it seems broadly clear that
free, open economies typically work better than closed, centrally
planned, heavily taxed ones. (5) Beyond that, though,
working out what works best is difficult.
Bergin concludes by wondering if the whole economics profession
needs taking down several pegs. Let pragmatism be the watchword,
laced with humility: "When economists are involved in
policymaking, their most valuable contribution often comes when
they leave economic theory at the door."
This is a fine book that challenges a number of assumptions,
although I found myself disputing some of his own
arguments. I think one lesson is that if one wants free
markets, low taxes and so on, these are often political, even
ethical arguments, and not just ones that can be decided by
plotting data on a chart. Bergin has fired a praiseworthy
warning shot at those who put too much confidence in
models. The quality of public policy should be all the
better for it, and once this lockdown nightmare is over, I look
forward to chatting to Tom about it over a beer or two.
References,
1,
https://www.adamsmith.org/research/austrian-economics-a-primer
2, https://www.gov.uk/national-minimum-wage-rates
3, The claim that Rockefeller and many other contemporaries were
“robbers” at the expense of the public has been challenged.
https://www.amazon.co.uk/Myth-Robber-Barons-Business-America-ebook/dp/B004X2IJ72
4, Bergin, as part of this argument, cites data in footnotes
claiming that entrepreneurs haven’t referred to tax rates as
affecting their decision to start a business in the first place,
innovate, etc. That claim appears to be contradicted, for
example, by economists Nir Jaimovich and Sergio Rebelo.
https://www.journals.uchicago.edu/doi/pdfplus/10.1086/689607
See also here for an overview of tax rates and the impact on
innovation:
https://www.thecgo.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/04/rif-2019.006.pdf
5, https://www.amazon.co.uk/Power-Capitalism-Rainer-Zitelmann/dp/191255500X